Difference between revisions of "Infinite game"
Squinterodlr (talk | contribs) m (Changed equations to TeX encoding.) |
|||
(2 intermediate revisions by one other user not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
+ | {{TEX|done}} | ||
A [[Non-cooperative game|non-cooperative game]], in particular a [[Two-person zero-sum game|two-person zero-sum game]], with infinite sets of player strategies. Let | A [[Non-cooperative game|non-cooperative game]], in particular a [[Two-person zero-sum game|two-person zero-sum game]], with infinite sets of player strategies. Let | ||
$$\Gamma = (X_1,X_2,...,X_n,H_1,H_2,...,H_n)$$ | $$\Gamma = (X_1,X_2,...,X_n,H_1,H_2,...,H_n)$$ | ||
− | be an infinite game with $n$ participants. It was shown by C. Berge [[#References|[1]]] that if $X_1,X_2,...X_n$ are locally convex compact linear topological Hausdorff spaces, if the pay-off functions $H_i$ are continuous on $\Pi_{i=1 | + | be an infinite game with $n$ participants. It was shown by C. Berge [[#References|[1]]] that if $X_1,X_2,...X_n$ are locally convex compact linear topological Hausdorff spaces, if the pay-off functions $H_i$ are continuous on $\Pi_{i=1}^n X_i$ and are quasi-concave for $x_i \in X_i$, $i=1,2,...,n$, then the game $\Gamma$ has equilibrium points (solutions). It was also shown [[#References|[2]]] that if the $X_i$ are compact Hausdorff spaces and the $H_i$ are continuous on $\Pi_{i=1}^n X_i$, $i=1,2,...,n$, then $\Gamma$ has equilibrium points in mixed strategies. However, not all infinite games have equilibrium points, even in mixed strategies. For example, for the two-person zero-sum game in which the sets of player strategies are sets of integers, while the pay-off function has the form |
$$H(m,n)= \begin{cases} | $$H(m,n)= \begin{cases} | ||
Line 15: | Line 16: | ||
====References==== | ====References==== | ||
− | <table><TR><TD valign="top">[1]</TD> <TD valign="top"> C. Berge, "Théorie génerale des jeux à | + | <table><TR><TD valign="top">[1]</TD> <TD valign="top"> C. Berge, "Théorie génerale des jeux à $n$ personnes" , Gauthier-Villars (1957)</TD></TR><TR><TD valign="top">[2]</TD> <TD valign="top"> I.L. Gliksberg, "A further generalization of the Kakutani fixed point theorem with application to Nash equilibrium points" ''Proc. Amer. Math. Soc.'' , '''3''' : 1 (1952) pp. 170–174</TD></TR></table> |
Latest revision as of 17:56, 25 November 2012
A non-cooperative game, in particular a two-person zero-sum game, with infinite sets of player strategies. Let
$$\Gamma = (X_1,X_2,...,X_n,H_1,H_2,...,H_n)$$
be an infinite game with $n$ participants. It was shown by C. Berge [1] that if $X_1,X_2,...X_n$ are locally convex compact linear topological Hausdorff spaces, if the pay-off functions $H_i$ are continuous on $\Pi_{i=1}^n X_i$ and are quasi-concave for $x_i \in X_i$, $i=1,2,...,n$, then the game $\Gamma$ has equilibrium points (solutions). It was also shown [2] that if the $X_i$ are compact Hausdorff spaces and the $H_i$ are continuous on $\Pi_{i=1}^n X_i$, $i=1,2,...,n$, then $\Gamma$ has equilibrium points in mixed strategies. However, not all infinite games have equilibrium points, even in mixed strategies. For example, for the two-person zero-sum game in which the sets of player strategies are sets of integers, while the pay-off function has the form
$$H(m,n)= \begin{cases} 1, & m>n\\ 0, & m=n\\ -1, & m<n\\ \end{cases}$$
no value exists. The best studied classes of infinite games in normal form are infinite two-person zero-sum games and, in particular, games on the unit square (cf. Game on the unit square).
References
[1] | C. Berge, "Théorie génerale des jeux à $n$ personnes" , Gauthier-Villars (1957) |
[2] | I.L. Gliksberg, "A further generalization of the Kakutani fixed point theorem with application to Nash equilibrium points" Proc. Amer. Math. Soc. , 3 : 1 (1952) pp. 170–174 |
Infinite game. Encyclopedia of Mathematics. URL: http://encyclopediaofmath.org/index.php?title=Infinite_game&oldid=28797