L-matrix
Matrices playing a central role in the study of qualitative economics and first defined by P.A. Samuelson [a6]. A real -matrix A is an L-matrix provided every matrix with the same sign pattern as A has linearly independent rows. For example,
\begin{equation*} M = \left( \begin{array} { c c c } { 1 } & { - 1 } & { 0 } \\ { 1 } & { 1 } & { - 1 } \\ { 1 } & { 1 } & { 1 } \end{array} \right) , \quad N = \left( \begin{array} { c c c c } { 1 } & { 1 } & { 1 } & { - 1 } \\ { 1 } & { 1 } & { - 1 } & { 1 } \\ { 1 } & { - 1 } & { 1 } & { 1 } \end{array} \right) \end{equation*}
are L-matrices. A linear system of equations, A x = b, is called sign-solvable provided the signs of the entries in any solution can be determined knowing only the signs of the entries in A and b. If the linear system A x = b is sign-solvable, then A ^ { T } is an L-matrix. General references for this area include [a1], [a3] and [a4].
The study of L-matrices has included characterizations of structural properties, classification of subclasses as well as interrelationships with other discrete structures. For example, two subclasses of L-matrices which arise are that of the barely L-matrices and the totally L-matrices.
An ( m \times n )-matrix A is a barely L-matrix provided that A is an L-matrix but if any column of it is deleted, the resulting matrix is not an L-matrix.
An ( m \times n )-matrix A is a totally L-matrix provided that each ( m \times m )-submatrix of A is an L-matrix.
The two matrices M and N above are examples of barely L-matrices. The matrix M is also a totally L-matrix but N is not since its ( 3 \times 3 )-submatrix made up of the first three columns is not an L-matrix. The matrix
\begin{equation*} T = \left( \begin{array} { c c c c } { 1 } & { 1 } & { 1 } & { 0 } \\ { 1 } & { - 1 } & { 0 } & { 1 } \end{array} \right) \end{equation*}
is a ( 2 \times 4 ) totally L-matrix.
The property of being a barely L-matrix, or a totally L-matrix, imposes restrictions on the number of columns. If A is an ( m \times n ) barely L-matrix, then the number of columns is at most 2 ^ { m - 1 }; further, if A has only non-negative entries, then the number of columns is at most
\begin{equation*} \left( \begin{array} { c } { m } \\ { \lceil \frac { m + 1 } { 2 } \rceil } \end{array} \right). \end{equation*}
If A is an ( m \times n ) totally L-matrix, then the number of columns is at most m + 2. It has been shown that the set of all m by m + 2 totally L-matrices can be obtained from the matrix T above by performing certain extension operations on T successively [a2].
An important subclass of the L-matrices for which there exist a great deal of literature is that of the square L-matrices, which are also called sign-non-singular matrices.
References
[a1] | L. Bassett, J. Maybee, J. Quirk, "Qualitative economics and the scope of the correspondence principle" Econometrica , 36 (1968) pp. 544–563 |
[a2] | R.A. Brualdi, K.L. Chavey, B.L. Shader, "Rectangular L-matrices" Linear Algebra Appl. , 196 (1994) pp. 37–61 |
[a3] | R.A. Brualdi, B.L. Shader, "Matrices of sign solvable systems" , Tracts in Math. , 116 , Cambridge Univ. Press (1995) |
[a4] | V. Klee, R. Ladner, R. Manber, "Sign-solvability revisited" Linear Algebra Appl. , 59 (1984) pp. 131–157 |
[a5] | R. Manber, "Graph-theoretical approach to qualitative solvability of linear systems" Linear Algebra Appl. , 48 (1982) pp. 131–157 |
[a6] | P.A. Samuelson, "Foundations of economic analysis" , Economic Studies , 80 , Harvard Univ. Press (1947) |
L-matrix. Encyclopedia of Mathematics. URL: http://encyclopediaofmath.org/index.php?title=L-matrix&oldid=49877